Cognitive mapping the topic of national innovation
system
Joseph
Kim-keung Ho
Independent Trainer
Hong Kong, China
Abstract: The topic of national
innovation system in the subject of Business Management is complex. By making
use of the cognitive mapping technique to conduct a brief literature review on
the national innovation system topic, the writer renders a systemic image on
the topic of national innovation system. The result of the study, in the form
of a cognitive map on national innovation system, should be useful to those who
are interested in the topics of cognitive mapping, literature review and national
innovation system.
Key words: National
innovation system, cognitive mapping, literature review
Introduction
As a
topic in Business Management, national innovation system is complex. It is thus
useful to employ some learning tool to conduct its study, notably for
literature review purpose. For a teacher in research methods, systems thinking
and management, the writer is specifically interested in finding out how the
cognitive mapping technique can be employed to go through a literature review
on national innovation system. This
literature review exercise is taken up and reported in this article.
On the cognitive mapping exercise for
literature review
Literature
review is an important intellectual learning exercise, and not just for doing
final year dissertation projects for tertiary education students. On these two
topics of intellectual learning and literature review, the writer has compiled
some e-learning resources. They are the Managerial
intellectual learning Facebook page and the Literature on literature review Facebook page. Conducting
literature review with the cognitive mapping technique is not novel in the
cognitive mapping literature, see Eden and Simpson (1989), Eden, Jones and Sims
(1983), Open University (n.d) and the Literature
on cognitive mapping Facebook page. In this article, the specific steps
involved in the cognitive mapping exercise are as follows:
Step 1:
gather some main points from a number of academic journal articles on National
innovation system. This result in the production of a table (Table 1) with the
main points and associated references.
Step 2: consolidate the main points from Table 1 to come up with
a table listing the cognitive map variables (re: Table 2).
Step 3: link
up the cognitive map variables in a
plausible way to produce a cognitive map (re: Figure 1) on the topic under
review.
The next
section applies these three steps to produce a cognitive map on national
innovation system.
Descriptions of cognitive map variables on
the national innovation system topic
From the
reading of some academic articles on National innovation system, a number of
main points (e.g., viewpoints, concepts and empirical findings) were gathered
by the writer. They are shown in Table 1
with explicit referencing on the points.
Table 1: Main
points from the national innovation system literature and referencing
Main points from the national innovation
system literature
|
Referencing
|
Point 1: "The
concept of national innovation systems arose in the late 1980s and early
1990s due to the dissatisfaction of a number of economists in the neoclassical
mainstream of economic theory and the inadequacy of the interpretations of
the role of technology, knowledge, and innovations in economic development
within the standard mainstream approaches (Sharif, 2006). Currently, the
concept of a national innovation system (NIS) covers all the major components
of the innovation process, including organizational, social, political, and
economic factors. This concept is widely used by researchers and decision
makers at the regional, national, and international levels".
|
Golichenko, O.G. 2016. "The National Innovation System: From Concept to Research
Methodology" Problems of
Economic Transition 58(5),
Routledge: 463-481.
|
Point 2: "... despite the successful
spread of the concept [of national innovation system] in the economic and
administrative environment, the very fact of its appearance has raised a
number of questions. How necessary is this concept? What challenges faced by
modern economic theory and practice does it solve? Is it possible to rely
solely on the already known neoclassical mainstream approaches to solve the
problems of innovative development?".
|
Golichenko, O.G. 2016. "The National Innovation System: From Concept to Research
Methodology" Problems of
Economic Transition 58(5),
Routledge: 463-481.
|
Point 3: "From the 1950s to 1960s, the
majority of neoclassical scholars reduced technological progress to an
exogenous phenomenon that is external to the socioeconomic system. They
regarded it as a public good. It was not competitive, and it did not have the
property of exclusivity. In other words, the use of technology by particular
agents did not reduce the opportunity for its consumption by the other
agents, and all economic agents had the right to equal access to technology
regardless of who owned it".
|
Golichenko, O.G. 2016. "The National Innovation System: From Concept to Research
Methodology" Problems of
Economic Transition 58(5),
Routledge: 463-481.
|
Point 4: "Not long ago most economists believed that differences in development
levels across countries were to be explained by one single factor, namely
differences in the amount of accumulated capital per worker (Solow, 1956, see
Fagerberg, 1994 for an overview). However, from the 1960s onwards the idea
that differences in development are mainly caused by technological
differences received increasing support (Gerschenkron, 1962). This view was,
of course, consistent with the perspective on growth developed by Schumpeter
(1934, 1943), and during the 1980s a lot of new work on cross-country
differences in levels of development and growth performance inspired by this
perspective emerged".
|
Fagerberg, J. and M. Srholec. 2008. "National
innovation systems, capabilities and economic development" Research Policy 37, Elsevier:
1417-1435.
|
Point 5: "Authors that emphasize the
crucial role of technology for development tend to stress that catching up in
technology is by no means a free ride. According to this perspective,
countries that do not succeed in developing appropriate technological
capabilities and other complementary factors should be expected to continue
to lag behind. Concepts such as “social capability” (Ohkawa and Rosovsky,
1974; Abramovitz, 1986), “technological capability” (Kim, 1980, 1997),
“absorptive capacity” (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990) and “innovation system”
(Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1993; Edquist, 1997) have been suggested and a burgeoning
empirical literature has emerged focusing on these aspects of
development".
|
Fagerberg, J. and M. Srholec. 2008. "National
innovation systems, capabilities and economic development" Research Policy 37, Elsevier:
1417-1435.
|
Point 6: "Moses Abramovitz, arguing
along similar lines as Gerschenkron, suggested that differences in countries’
abilities to exploit the potential for catch-up may to a large extent be explained
by differences in what he called “social capability”. What he had in mind was
not so much individual skills, important as these may be, but rather what
organizations in the private and public sector are capable of doing and how
this is supported (or hampered) by broader societal factors. These are some
of the aspects of social capability that he emphasized as being particularly
important: - managerial and technical competence; - a stable and effective
government, capable of supporting economic growth; - financial institutions
and markets capable of mobilizing capital on a large scale; - the spread of
honesty and trust in the population".
|
Fagerberg, J. and M. Srholec. 2008. "National
innovation systems, capabilities and economic development" Research Policy 37, Elsevier:
1417-1435.
|
Point 7: "In most accounts, the NIS [national
innovation system] concept is described as that set of national institutions
which contribute to generation and diffusion of new technologies and which
provide the framework within which government and firms negotiate policies to
influence the innovation process".
|
Watkins, A., T. Papaioannou, J. Mugwagwa
and D. Kale. 2015. "National innovation systems and intermediary role of
industry associations in building institutional capacities for innovation n
developing countries: A critical review of the literature" Research Policy 44, Elsevier:
1407-1418.
|
Point 8: "Although notions of
technological ‘catch-up’ and economic growth have always been central to the
NIS [national innovation system] concept (see Lundvall, 2007), the idea was
conceived on institutional structures and activities identified in already
developed countries (e.g., Japan, USA, Germany, Sweden) with developing
countries largely absent from the early literature. Shortly thereafter, the
NIS concept was applied to so-called newly industrialised countries (e.g.,
South Korea, Taiwan, and Singapore) and countries of Latin America (e.g., Mexico
and Argentina), and has, more recently, been applied to developing countries,
both the emerging powers of Brazil, India, China, and South Africa, and more
limitedly to less developed countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and
elsewhere".
|
Watkins, A., T. Papaioannou, J. Mugwagwa
and D. Kale. 2015. "National innovation systems and intermediary role of
industry associations in building institutional capacities for innovation n
developing countries: A critical review of the literature" Research Policy 44, Elsevier:
1407-1418.
|
Point 9: "Derived in part from the
ideas of List (1841) and his concept of national systems of production, the
NIS [national innovation system] concept was first proposed by Freeman (1982,
1987) as a response to the Washington consensus and to the neoclassical
approaches to growth. In this way, the NIS concept has always been
intrinsically linked to public policy (Sharif, 2006). Drawing on the work of
Nelson and Winter (1982) and their Schumpeterian inspired theory of economic
growth through evolutionary technological change, Freeman, along with Lundvall
(1985, 1988) and again Nelson (1988,1990), argued that neoclassical growth
models are inadequate as they ignored the role that technological change and
innovation play, particularly in economies that are science and technology
driven and which are increasingly shaped by competitive global forces".
|
Watkins, A., T. Papaioannou, J. Mugwagwa
and D. Kale. 2015. "National innovation systems and intermediary role of
industry associations in building institutional capacities for innovation n
developing countries: A critical review of the literature" Research Policy 44, Elsevier:
1407-1418.
|
Point 10: "While recent research has emphasised the importance
of National Innovation Systems or National Systems of Innovation (NIS/NSI)1
to the economic health of countries (Block & Keller 2008). The roots of
the empirical work on NIS are found in investigations into the interactions
between human capital, diffusion of technology and economic growth (Solow
1960; Nelson & Phelps 1966; Arrow 1996) and further back in terms of
Marshallan industrial districts (Marshall 1920)".
|
Bartels, F.L., H. Voss, S. Lederer and C. Bachtrog.
2012. "Determinants of National Innovation Systems: Policy implications
for developing countries" Innovation
14(1), Routledge: 2-18.
|
Point 11: "Within the debate concerning the institutions or
technology roots of economic growth (Nelson & Phelps 1966) NIS [national
innovation system] has become especially important in national policy since
1980 (European Commission 2004). This is reflected not only in public policy
support for small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) as sources of
innovation (Audretsch 2004) but also by the Community Innovation Surveys of
the EU2. NIS literature has expanded to cover multi-faceted dimensions in the
economics of technology, industrial performance and competitiveness and
innovation (including regional innovation systems, industrial dynamics and
structural change)".
|
Bartels, F.L., H. Voss, S. Lederer and C. Bachtrog.
2012. "Determinants of National Innovation Systems: Policy implications
for developing countries" Innovation
14(1), Routledge: 2-18.
|
Point 12: "The NIS [national innovation
system], as a widely accepted analytical framework for industrial innovation
on a national scale, draws attention to the importance of networks and links
between diverse institutions as a major factor behind the innovative capacity
of a nation. The way these diverse institutions interact with one another
within the NIS may be affected by the incentive schemes and institutional
arrangements and may thus lead to different innovation performances (Freeman,
1987; Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1993). In addition, although the NIS as an
analytical framework takes the nation as the unit of analysis, it does not
preclude the interaction between the domestic and foreign players".
|
Chen, S.H. 2007. "The national innovation system and foreign
R&D: the case of Taiwan" R&D
Management 37(5), Blackwell Publishing Ltd.: 441-453.
|
Point 13: "In a pioneer study on
Taiwan’s NIS, Hou and San (1993) drew attention to, among other things, the
role played by such a government-sponsored research institute as the
Industrial Technology Research Institute (ITRI) in promoting Taiwan’s IT
industry, by forging technological alliances with foreign partners and local
universities. However, Taiwan’s IT industry has become so well established as
to having moved from a focus on foreign technology to indigenous
innovation".
|
Chen, S.H. 2007. "The national innovation system and foreign
R&D: the case of Taiwan" R&D
Management 37(5), Blackwell Publishing Ltd.: 441-453.
|
Point 14: "As part of the socio-economic reform in the
People’s Republic of China (PRC) since 1978, the transformation of China’s
national innovation system (NIS) has resulted in rapid growth of innovative
outputs. Indeed, in 2012 worldwide patent applications from the PRC surpassed those
from the US. However, a closer look suggests that individual units of Chinese
innovative output are of lower than average quality according to various
metrics".
|
Schmid, J. and F.L. Wang. 2017.
"Beyond National Innovation Systems: Incentives and China's Innovation
Performance" Journal of
Contemporary China 26(104), Routledge: 280-296.
|
Point 15: "In essence, a country’s NIS
[national innovation system] refers to the combination of actors,
institutions and linkages that create and diffuse new scientific knowledge
and technology.2 More precisely, a country’s NIS refers to the public and
private actors—firms, government agencies and universities—and the
relationships between them—financial, technical and social—that have as
amongst their objectives the advancement or diffusion of technological
progress or scientific discovery".
|
Schmid, J. and F.L. Wang. 2017.
"Beyond National Innovation Systems: Incentives and China's Innovation
Performance" Journal of
Contemporary China 26(104), Routledge: 280-296.
|
Point 16: "A country’s NIS [national
innovation system] is most commonly evaluated by considering the
effectiveness by which it generates, diffuses and commercializes knowledge.
While no perfect measures of these processes currently exist, the metrics
used here—patent applications and scientific publications—approximate
national performance in these areas".
|
Schmid, J. and F.L. Wang. 2017.
"Beyond National Innovation Systems: Incentives and China's Innovation
Performance" Journal of
Contemporary China 26(104), Routledge: 280-296.
|
Point 17: "The National Innovation System (NIS) of a
country is composed of different subsystems, ranging from the economic
regime, financial structure and physical
infrastructure, to the education system, cultural traditions and so on. Thus,
economic development is regarded as the interaction and co-evolutionary
process of these subsystems (Freeman 1987; Nelson 1993). Lundvall (1992, 36)
defines the NIS as the elements and
relationships that interact in the production, diffusion and use of new and
economically useful knowledge and are either located within or rooted inside the
borders of a nation state".
|
Afzal, M.N.I. 2014. "An empirical investigation
of the National Innovation System (NIS) using Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA)
and the TOBIT model" International
Review of Applied Economics 28(4), Routledge: 507-523.
|
Point 18: "Furman, Porter, and Stern
(2002) investigated a formal empirical analysis in NIS studies called ‘national innovative capacity’. His empirical analysis was
based on three NIS theories: endogenous growth theory (see for example, Romer
1990), Porter’s theory of international competitiveness
(Porter 1990), and the national systems of innovation introduced by Lundvall
(1992). Furman’s national innovative capacity illustrated
a country’s innovation ability to produce and
commercialise new ideas over a long period of time".
|
Afzal, M.N.I. 2014. "An empirical
investigation of the National Innovation System (NIS) using Data Envelopment
Analysis (DEA) and the TOBIT model" International
Review of Applied Economics 28(4), Routledge: 507-523.
|
Point 19: "... the
systemic view of national systems of innovation is not fully explored by researchers
in their inquiry of national systems of innovation. A careful scrutiny of the
current literature on national systems of innovation reveals that instead of
developing a unifying framework, extant research examining national systems
of innovation usually take different approaches (e.g. structural approach,
functional approach and effective approach) (Balzat and Hanusch, 2004). The
lack of integrated framework on the one hand impedes our further
understanding on the national systems of innovation, while on the other hand,
it might also mislead the policymaking process".
|
Wang, Y. and Z. Zhou. 2011. "Building
an integrative framework for national systems of innovation" Journal of Knowledge-based Innovation in
China 3(3), Emerald: 160-171.
|
With a
set of main points collected, the writer produces a set of cognitive map
variables. These variables are informed by the set of main points from Table 1.
These variables are presented in Table 2.
Table 2:
Cognitive map variables based on Table 1
Cognitive
map variables
|
Literature
review points
|
Variable 1: Drivers of interest in national
innovation system
|
Point 1: "The
concept of national innovation systems arose in the late 1980s and early
1990s due to the dissatisfaction of a number of economists in the neoclassical
mainstream of economic theory and the inadequacy of the interpretations of
the role of technology, knowledge, and innovations in economic development
within the standard mainstream approaches (Sharif, 2006). Currently, the
concept of a national innovation system (NIS) covers all the major components
of the innovation process, including organizational, social, political, and
economic factors. This concept is widely used by researchers and decision
makers at the regional, national, and international levels".
Point 3: "From the 1950s to 1960s, the
majority of neoclassical scholars reduced technological progress to an
exogenous phenomenon that is external to the socioeconomic system. They
regarded it as a public good. It was not competitive, and it did not have the
property of exclusivity. In other words, the use of technology by particular
agents did not reduce the opportunity for its consumption by the other
agents, and all economic agents had the right to equal access to technology
regardless of who owned it".
Point 4: "Not long ago most economists believed that differences in development
levels across countries were to be explained by one single factor, namely
differences in the amount of accumulated capital per worker (Solow, 1956, see
Fagerberg, 1994 for an overview). However, from the 1960s onwards the idea
that differences in development are mainly caused by technological
differences received increasing support (Gerschenkron, 1962). This view was,
of course, consistent with the perspective on growth developed by Schumpeter
(1934, 1943), and during the 1980s a lot of new work on cross-country
differences in levels of development and growth performance inspired by this
perspective emerged".
Point 8: "Although notions of
technological ‘catch-up’ and economic growth have always been central to the
NIS [national innovation system] concept (see Lundvall, 2007), the idea was
conceived on institutional structures and activities identified in already
developed countries (e.g., Japan, USA, Germany, Sweden) with developing
countries largely absent from the early literature. Shortly thereafter, the
NIS concept was applied to so-called newly industrialised countries (e.g.,
South Korea, Taiwan, and Singapore) and countries of Latin America (e.g., Mexico
and Argentina), and has, more recently, been applied to developing countries,
both the emerging powers of Brazil, India, China, and South Africa, and more
limitedly to less developed countries in Sub-Saharan Africa and
elsewhere".
|
Variable 2: Improve intellectual
understanding of national innovation system
|
Point 5: "Authors that emphasize the
crucial role of technology for development tend to stress that catching up in
technology is by no means a free ride. According to this perspective,
countries that do not succeed in developing appropriate technological
capabilities and other complementary factors should be expected to continue
to lag behind. Concepts such as “social capability” (Ohkawa and Rosovsky,
1974; Abramovitz, 1986), “technological capability” (Kim, 1980, 1997),
“absorptive capacity” (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990) and “innovation system”
(Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1993; Edquist, 1997) have been suggested and a burgeoning
empirical literature has emerged focusing on these aspects of
development".
Point 7: "In most accounts, the NIS [national
innovation system] concept is described as that set of national institutions
which contribute to generation and diffusion of new technologies and which
provide the framework within which government and firms negotiate policies to
influence the innovation process".
Point 9: "Derived in part from the
ideas of List (1841) and his concept of national systems of production, the
NIS [national innovation system] concept was first proposed by Freeman (1982,
1987) as a response to the Washington consensus and to the neoclassical
approaches to growth. In this way, the NIS concept has always been
intrinsically linked to public policy (Sharif, 2006). Drawing on the work of
Nelson and Winter (1982) and their Schumpeterian inspired theory of economic
growth through evolutionary technological change, Freeman, along with Lundvall
(1985, 1988) and again Nelson (1988,1990), argued that neoclassical growth
models are inadequate as they ignored the role that technological change and
innovation play, particularly in economies that are science and technology
driven and which are increasingly shaped by competitive global forces".
Point 10: "While recent research has emphasised the importance
of National Innovation Systems or National Systems of Innovation (NIS/NSI)1
to the economic health of countries (Block & Keller 2008). The roots of
the empirical work on NIS are found in investigations into the interactions
between human capital, diffusion of technology and economic growth (Solow
1960; Nelson & Phelps 1966; Arrow 1996) and further back in terms of
Marshallan industrial districts (Marshall 1920)".
Point 12: "The NIS [national innovation
system], as a widely accepted analytical framework for industrial innovation
on a national scale, draws attention to the importance of networks and links
between diverse institutions as a major factor behind the innovative capacity
of a nation. The way these diverse institutions interact with one another
within the NIS may be affected by the incentive schemes and institutional
arrangements and may thus lead to different innovation performances (Freeman,
1987; Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1993). In addition, although the NIS as an
analytical framework takes the nation as the unit of analysis, it does not
preclude the interaction between the domestic and foreign players".
Point 15: "In essence, a country’s NIS
[national innovation system] refers to the combination of actors,
institutions and linkages that create and diffuse new scientific knowledge
and technology.2 More precisely, a country’s NIS refers to the public and
private actors—firms, government agencies and universities—and the
relationships between them—financial, technical and social—that have as
amongst their objectives the advancement or diffusion of technological
progress or scientific discovery".
Point 17: "The National Innovation System (NIS) of a
country is composed of different subsystems, ranging from the economic
regime, financial structure and physical
infrastructure, to the education system, cultural traditions and so on. Thus,
economic development is regarded as the interaction and co-evolutionary
process of these subsystems (Freeman 1987; Nelson 1993). Lundvall (1992, 36)
defines the NIS as the elements and
relationships that interact in the production, diffusion and use of new and
economically useful knowledge and are either located within or rooted inside the
borders of a nation state".
Point 18: "Furman, Porter, and Stern
(2002) investigated a formal empirical analysis in NIS studies called ‘national innovative capacity’. His empirical analysis was
based on three NIS theories: endogenous growth theory (see for example, Romer
1990), Porter’s theory of international competitiveness
(Porter 1990), and the national systems of innovation introduced by Lundvall
(1992). Furman’s national innovative capacity illustrated
a country’s innovation ability to produce and
commercialise new ideas over a long period of time".
Point 19: "... the
systemic view of national systems of innovation is not fully explored by researchers
in their inquiry of national systems of innovation. A careful scrutiny of the
current literature on national systems of innovation reveals that instead of
developing a unifying framework, extant research examining national systems
of innovation usually take different approaches (e.g. structural approach,
functional approach and effective approach) (Balzat and Hanusch, 2004). The
lack of integrated framework on the one hand impedes our further
understanding on the national systems of innovation, while on the other hand,
it might also mislead the policymaking process".
|
Variable 3: Effective national
innovation system practices
|
Point 6: "Moses Abramovitz, arguing
along similar lines as Gerschenkron, suggested that differences in countries’
abilities to exploit the potential for catch-up may to a large extent be explained
by differences in what he called “social capability”. What he had in mind was
not so much individual skills, important as these may be, but rather what
organizations in the private and public sector are capable of doing and how
this is supported (or hampered) by broader societal factors. These are some
of the aspects of social capability that he emphasized as being particularly
important: - managerial and technical competence; - a stable and effective
government, capable of supporting economic growth; - financial institutions
and markets capable of mobilizing capital on a large scale; - the spread of
honesty and trust in the population".
Point 11: "Within the debate concerning the institutions or
technology roots of economic growth (Nelson & Phelps 1966) NIS [national
innovation system] has become especially important in national policy since
1980 (European Commission 2004). This is reflected not only in public policy
support for small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) as sources of
innovation (Audretsch 2004) but also by the Community Innovation Surveys of
the EU2. NIS literature has expanded to cover multi-faceted dimensions in the
economics of technology, industrial performance and competitiveness and
innovation (including regional innovation systems, industrial dynamics and
structural change)".
Point 13: "In a pioneer study on
Taiwan’s NIS, Hou and San (1993) drew attention to, among other things, the
role played by such a government-sponsored research institute as the
Industrial Technology Research Institute (ITRI) in promoting Taiwan’s IT
industry, by forging technological alliances with foreign partners and local
universities. However, Taiwan’s IT industry has become so well established as
to having moved from a focus on foreign technology to indigenous
innovation".
|
Variable 4: Learn from national
innovation system practices
|
Point 2: "... despite the successful
spread of the concept [of national innovation system] in the economic and
administrative environment, the very fact of its appearance has raised a
number of questions. How necessary is this concept? What challenges faced by
modern economic theory and practice does it solve? Is it possible to rely
solely on the already known neoclassical mainstream approaches to solve the
problems of innovative development?".
Point 14: "As part of the socio-economic reform in the
People’s Republic of China (PRC) since 1978, the transformation of China’s
national innovation system (NIS) has resulted in rapid growth of innovative
outputs. Indeed, in 2012 worldwide patent applications from the PRC surpassed those
from the US. However, a closer look suggests that individual units of Chinese
innovative output are of lower than average quality according to various
metrics".
Point 16: "A country’s NIS [national
innovation system] is most commonly evaluated by considering the
effectiveness by which it generates, diffuses and commercializes knowledge.
While no perfect measures of these processes currently exist, the metrics
used here—patent applications and scientific publications—approximate
national performance in these areas".
|
The next
step is to relate the cognitive map variables to make up a cognitive map on national
innovation system. The cognitive map and its explanation are presented in the
next section.
A cognitive map on national innovation
system and its interpretation
By
relating the four variables identified in Table 2, the writer comes up with a
cognitive map on national innovation system, as shown in Figure 1.
These
cognitive map variables, four of them
altogether, are related to constitute a systemic image of national innovation
system. The links in the cognitive map (re: Figure 1) indicate direction of
influences between variables. The + sign shows that an increase in one variable
leads to an increase in another variable while a -ve sign tells us that in
increase in one variable leads to a decrease in another variable. If there no signs shown on the arrows, that means
the influences can be positive or negative. For further information on national innovation
system, readers are referred to the Literature
on national innovation system Facebook page.
Concluding remarks
The
cognitive mapping exercise captures in one diagram some of the main variables
involved in national innovation system. The resultant cognitive map promotes an
exploratory way to study national innovation system in a holistic tone. The
experience of the cognitive mapping exercise is that it can be a quick,
efficient and entertaining way to explore a complex topic such as national
innovation system in Business Management. Finally, readers who are interested
in cognitive mapping should also find the article informative on this mapping
topic.
Bibliography
1.
Afzal, M.N.I. 2014. "An empirical investigation of the National
Innovation System (NIS) using Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) and the TOBIT
model" International Review of
Applied Economics 28(4), Routledge: 507-523.
2.
Bartels, F.L., H. Voss, S. Lederer and C. Bachtrog. 2012.
"Determinants of National Innovation Systems: Policy implications for
developing countries" Innovation 14(1),
Routledge: 2-18.
3.
Chen, S.H. 2007. "The
national innovation system and foreign R&D: the case of Taiwan" R&D Management 37(5), Blackwell
Publishing Ltd.: 441-453.
4.
Eden, C. and P.
Simpson. 1989. "SODA and cognitive mapping in practice", pp. 43-70,
in Rosenhead, J. (editor) Rational
Analysis for a Problematic World, Wiley, Chichester.
5.
Eden, C., C. Jones
and D. Sims. 1983. Messing about in
Problems: An informal structured approach to their identification and
management, Pergamon Press, Oxford.
6.
Fagerberg, J. and M. Srholec. 2008. "National innovation systems,
capabilities and economic development" Research
Policy 37, Elsevier: 1417-1435.
7.
Golichenko, O.G. 2016. "The National Innovation System: From Concept to Research
Methodology" Problems of
Economic Transition 58(5),
Routledge: 463-481.
8.
Literature on cognitive mapping Facebook page, maintained by Joseph, K.K. Ho (url address: https://www.facebook.com/Literature-on-cognitive-mapping-800894476751355/).
9. Literature on
literature review Facebook page, maintained by Joseph, K.K. Ho (url address: https://www.facebook.com/literature.literaturereview/).
10. Literature on
national innovation system Facebook page, maintained by Joseph, K.K. Ho (url address: https://www.facebook.com/Literature-on-national-innovation-system-184917495380183/).
11. Managerial intellectual learning
Facebook page, maintained by Joseph, K.K. Ho (url address:
https://www.facebook.com/managerial.intellectual.learning/).
12. Open University. n.d. "Sign graph" Systems Thinking and Practice (T552): Diagramming, Open University,
U.K. (url address: http://systems.open.ac.uk/materials/T552/) [visited at April
10, 2017].
13. Schmid, J. and F.L. Wang. 2017.
"Beyond National Innovation Systems: Incentives and China's Innovation
Performance" Journal of Contemporary
China 26(104), Routledge: 280-296.
14. Wang, Y. and Z. Zhou. 2011.
"Building an integrative framework for national systems of
innovation" Journal of
Knowledge-based Innovation in China 3(3), Emerald: 160-171.
15. Watkins, A., T. Papaioannou, J.
Mugwagwa and D. Kale. 2015. "National innovation systems and intermediary
role of industry associations in building institutional capacities for
innovation n developing countries: A critical review of the literature" Research Policy 44, Elsevier: 1407-1418.
No comments:
Post a Comment