A study note on knowledge-uncertainty-based learning
regarding strategic management
Issues and related key words in Strategic Management
research: a sample of academic articles, sorted in chronological order
Years
of publication
|
Issues
and knowledge gaps as recognized in strategic management academic articles:
extracts from the Strategic Management Journal
|
Key
words involved
|
Article 1
1998
|
“A ‘customer orientation’ has been criticized for contributing to many
things including incremental and trivial product development efforts (Bennett
and Cooper, 1979), myopic R&D programs (Frosch, 1996), confused business
processes (Macdonald, 1995), and even a decline in America’s industrial
competitiveness (Hayes and Wheelwright, 1984). Christensen and Bower (1996:
198) add their voices to this chorus in their analysis of the impact of
disruptive technologies on industry evolution when they conclude that ‘firms
lose their position of industry leadership % because they listen too carefully to their customers.’ However, these
views are seemingly at odds with the marketing concept that is the foundation
of modern marketing. The marketing concept says that an organization’s purpose
is to discover needs and wants in its target markets and to satisfy those
needs more effectively and efficiently than competitors”;
STANLEY F. SLATER1* AND JOHN C. NARVER.
1998. “RESEARCH
NOTES AND COMMUNICATIONS: CUSTOMER-LED
AND MARKET-ORIENTED: LET’S NOT CONFUSE THE TWO” Strat. Mgmt. J., 19: 1001–1006.
|
Customer orientation
|
Article 2
1998
|
“Diversification by firms into unfamiliar product– markets is typically
achieved by internal development of a new business from ground up, by acquisition
of an existing business in the destination industry, or by some combination
of these two basic approaches. These different entry modes often pose
radically different options for firms contemplating diversification (cf. Yip,
1982).1 Recognizing that how entry is made is an important
consideration for diversifying firms, some researchers have examined the
motivations for and tendency of firms to rely generally on either acquisitive
or de novo mode (Amit, Livnat, and Zarowin, 1989; Lamont and Anderson,
1985), and some others have empirically tested the consequences of preferred
mode for aggregate firm performance (Simmonds, 1990; Busija, O’Neill, and
Zeithaml, 1997). In the main, concern in these studies has been with
determining the characteristics of firms that are more likely to pursue one
mode over the other. In addition, a few studies have also theorized about and
empirically examined factors that may drive the choice of either mode when
the circumstances surrounding individual entries are known (Chatterjee,
1990; Yip, 1982)”;
ANURAG SHARMA. 1998. “MODE OF ENTRY AND
EX-POST PERFORMANCE” Strat.
Mgmt. J., 19, 879–900.
|
|
Article 3
1998
|
“Despite an unabated stream of research on strategic groups across a
wide range of industries, there is still little agreement over the research findings.
Critics question whether strategic groups exist and point to the absence of
consistent links between strategic groups and profits.1 Others complain of
limited theoretical development, the ad hoc nature of key concepts, poor
model specification, and problems of measurement.2 Perhaps the most critical
concern is whether the study of intraindustry groups provides any information
that cannot be gleaned from the study of industries and individual firms”;
DAVID DRANOVE1, MARGARET PETERAF2 and MARK SHANLEY.
1998. “DO
STRATEGIC GROUPS EXIST? AN ECONOMIC FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS” Strat. Mgmt. J., 19: 1029–1044.
|
|
Article 4
2000
|
“Two broad classes of explanations have been
offered to explain the formation of interfirm linkages or alliances between
potential competitors.1 One set of explanations has focused on the strategic or
resource needs of firms. According to this perspective firms form linkages to
obtain access to needed assets (Hagedoorn and Schakenraad, 1990; Harrigan,
1988; Nohria and Garcia-Pont, 1991), learn new skills (Baum, Calabrese, and
Silverman, 2000; Hennart, 1988; Kogut, 1988; Powell, Koput, and Smith-Doerr,
1996), manage their dependence upon other firms (Pfeffer and Salancik, 1978),
or maintain parity with competitors (Garcia-Pont and Nohria, 1999). Thus,
linkage formation reflects firms’ inducements or incentives to
collaborate. A second set of explanations of alliance formation behaviour has
come from the structural sociological perspective and has argued that the
patterns of observed interfirm linkages reflect the prior patterns of interfirm
relationships (Gulati, 1995b, 1999; Gulati and Gargiulo, 1999; Walker, Kogut,
and Shan, 1997). According to this view, a firm’s ability to form new
relationships is determined by the set of opportunities provided by
its position in the prior network structure. Although both perspectives
provide insights into linkage formation behavior, neither approach provides a
complete explanation. Researchers from the strategic needs or inducements
perspective have often assumed, implicitly or explicitly, that the
availability of opportunities is not a constraint and that the supply of
linkage partners is infinitely elastic (Arora and Gambardella, 1990; Hagedoorn
and Schakenraad, 1990). The validity of this assumption is debatable”;
GAUTAM AHUJA. 2000. “THE DUALITY OF
COLLABORATION: INDUCEMENTS AND OPPORTUNITIES IN THE FORMATION OF INTERFIRM
LINKAGES” Strat. Mgmt. J., 21: 317–343.
|
|
Article 5
2001
|
“As joint ventures (JVs) have become more central to parent firms’
corporate and international strategies, managing JV dynamics has also increased
in importance. How ventures evolve and ultimately terminate are relevant
strategy concerns since they affect parent firms’ boundaries, resource
allocation and development, and market commitments. However, little is known
about the consequences of JV dynamics for collaborators, chiefly because of
the literature’s historical focus on JV formation issues (e.g., Doz, 1996).
The resulting gap in understanding about JVs is significant because the
management of post-formation stages of collaboration may have an important
bearing on the total value the firm derives or
sacrifices from partnering (e.g., Doz and Hamel,
1998)”;
JEFFREY J. REUER. 2001. “FROM HYBRIDS TO
HIERARCHIES: SHAREHOLDER WEALTH EFFECTS OF JOINT VENTURE PARTNER BUYOUTS” Strat. Mgmt. J., 22: 27–44.
|
|
Article 6
2007
|
“Recent
scholarship stresses that business enterprises consist of portfolios of
idiosyncratic and difficult-to-trade assets and competencies (’resources’). 1
Within this framework, competitive advantage can flow at a point in time from the ownership of scarce but relevant
and difficult-to-imitate assets, especially know-how. However, in fast-moving
business environments open to global competition, and characterized by
dispersion in the geographical and organizational sources of innovation and
manufacturing, sustainable advantage requires more than the ownership
of difficult-to-replicate (knowledge) assets. It also requires unique and
difficult-to-replicate dynamic capabilities. These capabilities can be
harnessed to continuously create, extend, upgrade, protect, and keep relevant
the enterprise’s unique asset base”;
DAVID J. TEECE. 2007. “EXPLICATING
DYNAMIC CAPABILITIES: THE NATURE AND MICROFOUNDATIONS OF (SUSTAINABLE) ENTERPRISE
PERFORMANCE” Strat. Mgmt. J., 28:
1319–1350.
|
|
Article 7
2009
|
“How
are resources exchanged and status utilized between partners in strategic
alliances? What are the performance implications of such exchange mechanisms
for parent firms? The economic rationale for resource needs and the
sociological justification for status seeking represent two major streams of
research in strategic alliances, especially in the partner selection process.
Researchers who subscribe to the resource-based view (RBV) argue that
resources of particular interest in alliances include financial capital,
technical capabilities, managerial capabilities, and other relevant assets
(Hitt et al., 2000). Partners should be sufficiently differentiated
to provide missing elements or new/complementary capabilities (Osborn and Hagedoorn,
1997). Firms search for alliance partners with resources that they can
leverage and integrate to create synergy (Das, Sen, and Sengupta, 1998; Lin,
Yang, and Demirkan, 2007). Researchers who rely on the institutional
perspective instead argue for a normative rationality of partner selection,
contending that alliances are formed for the conformity of social
justification and social obligation (Zukin and Dimaggio, 1990)”;
ZHIANG (JOHN) LIN,1* HAIBIN YANG,2 and
BINDU ARYA. 2009. “ALLIANCE
PARTNERS AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: RESOURCE COMPLEMENTARITY AND STATUS ASSOCIATION” Strat. Mgmt. J., 30: 921–940.
|
|
Article 8
2009
|
“As
interest in alliance capability has grown, we see two streams of research
emerge over time that address different, but equally important, issues related
to this subject. The first research stream focuses on how alliance capability
develops in firms and investigates mechanisms that explain or lead to it
(Anand and Khanna, 2000; Kale, Dyer, and Singh, 2002; Kale and Singh, 2007).
A second research stream investigates what elements constitute a firm’s
alliance capability (Gulati, 1998), rather than study how it develops in
firms. Within this stream, the constituent elements of alliance capability
are being studied at two different levels: One set of scholars is focusing on
a firm and its entire portfolio
of alliances, and examining skills that comprise a firm’s capability to
manage such a portfolio of alliances—
they refer to it as alliance portfolio capability (Hoffmann, 2007). On the other hand, a
second set of scholars is focusing on individual alliances in firms and
trying to understand elements
that comprise its capability to handle or manage any individual alliance (Doz, 1996; Dyer and Singh, 1998)”;
MELANIE SCHREINER,1 PRASHANT KALE,2* and
DANIEL CORSTEN. 2009. “WHAT
REALLY IS ALLIANCE MANAGEMENT CAPABILITY AND HOW DOES IT IMPACT ALLIANCE OUTCOMES
AND SUCCESS?” Strat. Mgmt. J., 30:
1395–1419.
|
|
Article 9
2010
|
“A
hypercompetitive industry is ‘characterized by intense and rapid competitive
moves, in which competitors must move quickly to build advantage and erode
the advantage of their rivals’ (D’Aveni and Gunther, 1994: 217–218).
Frequent, bold, and aggressive competitive moves of rivals create a condition
of constant disequilibrium and change (D’Aveni and Gunther, 1994). In the battle for king of the hill, challengers quickly climb performance peaks
to dethrone the leaders (Ferrier, Smith, and Grimm, 1999; Smith, Ferrier, and
Grimm, 2001), only to find out in a few years that they are dethroned by new challengers. Performance rank orders
of firms change frequently (McAfee and Brynjolfsson, 2008). Proponents argue
that a wide range of industries has exhibited hypercompetition in recent
decades (Thomas, 1996; Wiggins and Ruefli, 2005). Skeptics argue that ‘hypercompetition
is a self-inflicted wound, not the inevitable outcome of a changing paradigm
of competition’ (Porter, 1996: 61). Some studies do not find empirical
evidence supporting broad-based, long-term increases in hypercompetition (Castrogiovanni,
2002; McNamara, Vaaler, and Devers, 2003). They argue that hypercompetition may
be limited to a subset of high-technology industries”;
CHI-HYON LEE,1* N. VENKATRAMAN,2 HU¨ SEYIN
TANRIVERDI,3 and BALA IYER. 2010. “COMPLEMENTARITY-BASED HYPERCOMPETITION IN THE
SOFTWARE INDUSTRY: THEORY AND EMPIRICAL TEST, 1990–2002” Strat. Mgmt. J., 31: 1431–1456.
|
|
Article 10
2011
|
“This
study analyzes differences in the innovativeness of subsidiaries of foreign
multinational enterprises (MNEs) in comparison to domestic companies
competing in the same country. There appear to be two conflicting views. On
the one hand, some research has argued that subsidiaries of foreign MNEs
(henceforth, ‘subsidiaries’) are at a disadvantage in comparison to domestic
firms because they suffer from a cost of doing business abroad (Hymer, 1976)
or a liability of foreignness (Zaheer, 1995). On the other hand, other
studies assume that subsidiaries have a technological advantage over domestic
firms because the former receive knowledge and technology from the MNE (e.g.,
Buckley and Casson, 1976; Vernon, 1966). Unfortunately, no studies have
compared their innovativeness and, thus, we still debate about whether they differ and why, and we are
unable to provide managers with proper guidance”;
C. ANNIQUE UN. 2011. “RESEARCH NOTES
AND COMMENTARIES THE ADVANTAGE OF FOREIGNNESS IN INNOVATION” Strat. Mgmt. J., 32:
1232–1242.
|
|
Article 11
2013
|
“Firm
performance hinges on the efficient and effective management of productive
resources using knowledge-based routines. Do these resource management
capabilities interact positively with resource quality and, thus, synergistically determine performance? A common perception
is that there must be complementarities to be harnessed among resources and
that by identifying and exploiting these, managers can add value to the firm.
There is, however, no strong theoretical basis for this view. Indeed, while
the independent effects of resources and resource management might be positive,
there may be no synergies, or worse, such interactions might be negative”;
MARCO D. HUESCH. 2013. “ARE THERE ALWAYS
SYNERGIES BETWEEN PRODUCTIVE RESOURCES AND RESOURCE DEPLOYMENT CAPABILITIES?”
Strat. Mgmt. J., 34:
1288–1313.
|
|
Article 12
2013
|
“How does deregulation affect strategic
choice? Regulation puts restrictions on firm behavior. Economic regulation,
for example, puts restrictions on firm decisions over price, quantity, entry,
and exit (Smith and Grimm, 1987). Accordingly, one would naturally expect
deregulation to open up previously untapped opportunities with few or no
regulatory constraints. For instance, regulation might stifle incentives to
innovate and differentiate, with deregulation opening up a new horizon in
these directions. Despite the increasing deregulation of formerly regulated
industries, such as telephone, natural gas, railroad, and electric power,
relatively little attention has been paid to this subject in the strategic
management literature (Delmas, Russo, and Montes-Sancho, 2007; Haveman, 1993;
Reger, Duhaime, and Stimpert, 1992; Russo, 1992; Silverman, Nickerson, and
Freeman, 1997; Smith and Grimm, 1987; Walker, Madsen, and Carini, 2002; Zajac
and Shortell, 1989)”;
EUN-HEE KIM. 2013. “DEREGULATION AND
DIFFERENTIATION: INCUMBENT INVESTMENT IN GREEN TECHNOLOGIES” Strat. Mgmt. J., 34:
1162–1185.
|
No comments:
Post a Comment